close
close
Wed. Oct 23rd, 2024

The Secret Economic Theory Behind the $100,000 Birkin Bag

The Secret Economic Theory Behind the 0,000 Birkin Bag

In 1984, Jean-Louis Dumas, CEO of a struggling French fashion house, was consumed with thoughts of how to not only revive but surpass the glory that Hermès had once known. Four years after his role, he couldn’t shake the idea that he had to capture lightning in a bottle again, as his father had done with the now legendary Kelly bag.

The story goes that Grace Kelly, the iconic actress and later Princess of Monaco, was photographed carrying an Hermès bag to discreetly hide her pregnancy from paparazzi. That one moment propelled the Kelly bag to fame, making it one of the very first “It bags” and making Hermès a force in luxury fashion.

But like all products, the Kelly bag reached its maturity stage in the product life cycle. When sales stagnated, Dumas knew he had two options: innovate the Kelly or create something new. While the Kelly bag maintained its place in the market, Hermès needed a new spark. Dumas, like many other marketers, thought, “I just need one more Grace Kelly.”

As fate would have it, his next muse sat next to him on a flight: a beautiful English actress and singer named Jane Birkin. But this wasn’t an accidental pregnancy moment or a coincidence of fate like Kelly’s. This time, Dumas took a more strategic approach: he created a product specifically for Birkin, whose carefree, bohemian style was the perfect counterpoint to Hermès’ structured elegance. This was no coincidence; this was calculated marketing genius.

The Birkin bag didn’t take off right away, just as its namesake wasn’t entirely taken with it at first. It was too heavy, too serious – too much in contrast to Birkin’s light, messy and quintessentially French charm. But Hermès knew better. With a strategy based on scarcity, exclusivity and careful association with the Birkin name, the product took off and catapulted Hermès into the luxury stratosphere.

We all know the tradition by now. Hermès shoppers can be placed on years-long waiting lists for that alone chance own a Birkin. As one scene in Sex and the city captured so perfectly: ‘It’s not a bag. It’s a Birkin.’ This wasn’t about functionality. It wasn’t even about craftsmanship anymore. The Birkin had transcended the realm of luxury handbags: it had become a symbol of unattainable wealth, desire and exclusivity.

So why does this bag, which honestly isn’t even the most aesthetically groundbreaking piece, have such a stranglehold on the market? The answer lies in the Austrian economy.

Mengers Theory of the good: Understanding subjective value

by Carl Menger Theory of the good is the basis for understanding why something like a Birkin can command such exorbitant prices. Value, Menger taught us, is subjective. It does not arise from the cost of materials or labor invested in the production of a good; it arises from the extent to which that good satisfies the individual’s desires.

In the case of the Birkin, the price tag does not depend solely on the materials or craftsmanship, although both are undoubtedly of high quality. Instead, its value is derived from the consumer’s perception of what a Birkin possesses resources. The exclusivity that Hermès has cultivated around the bag – along with the mythology surrounding Jane Birkin and the iconic status the brand has achieved – has increased its perceived value. It fulfills the consumer’s desire for status, prestige and belonging to an elite group.

Menger’s theory reminds us that the true value of the Birkin lies not in the bag itself, but in what it represents to the buyer. One person may be willing to pay tens of thousands of dollars for the Birkin because it satisfies his need for recognition and status, while another may see it as nothing more than an overpriced leather bag. This disparity in value perceptions is exactly what Menger meant by subjective value: goods have value only to the extent that they satisfy consumer desires.

Mises’ Human action: Goal-oriented decisions in marketing

Ludwig von Mises, building on Menger’s work, introduced us to the concept of human action– the idea that individuals act purposefully to achieve their goals. Every economic decision, according to Mises, is a calculated attempt to improve someone’s situation. This is especially relevant in the luxury market, where purchasing decisions often extend beyond utility.

Consider the purposeful nature of buying a Birkin. The person who buys the bag is not just buying an accessory, but investing in an identity. They make a calculated decision to radiate wealth, sophistication and exclusivity. For many, owning a Birkin isn’t about practicality; it’s about the message it sends to others. This decision is very intentional and reflects Mises’ principle that economic actions are rooted in individual goals and circumstances.

For us as marketers, understanding this is crucial. Consumers do not make purchases solely based on rational factors such as price or utility; they are driven by deeper, often emotional motivations. We must tailor our strategies to these personal, subjective goals – whether status, identity or self-expression – and create stories around products that resonate with these desires.

Rejecting predictive models: the Austrian critique

Austrian economists, especially Mises and Hayek, were outspoken critics of rigid, formulaic models that attempt to predict human behavior. They argued that human actions are too complex and individualistic to be reduced to simple equations. This insight is invaluable in the marketing world, where consumer behavior often defies predictive models.

Take the luxury market for example. While demographics may suggest who is buying a Birkin, they cannot explain it Why they buy it. The decision to spend thousands of dollars on a handbag is influenced by a host of personal factors – status aspirations, social pressure, emotional satisfaction – all of which are subjective and unique to the individual. No mathematical model can fully explain these motivations.

From an Austrian perspective, the Birkin’s success lies not in following a predictable formula, but in the brand’s ability to shape and cultivate consumer perception. Hermès does not sell products; they sell exclusivity, dreams and the feeling of belonging to an elite class. The value of the Birkin, like many luxury goods, is derived from these subjective, personal stories.

The Birkin as a case study in Austrian economics

Menger and Mises’ ideas come to life in the story of the Birkin. Mengers Theory of the good explains why the Birkin is valuable – not because of its intrinsic characteristics, but because of the subjective value that consumers place on it. The bag fulfills emotional and social desires and creates an aura of exclusivity that stimulates demand.

Mises’ human action The theory further illustrates why consumers willingly wait years and pay a premium for a product like the Birkin. Buying the bag is not about functionality; it is about fulfilling personal goals – whether that is signaling wealth or achieving a sense of belonging in an exclusive social group. This is a deliberate, purposeful action, driven by subjective goals.

Why Austrian economics is important for marketing

For those of us working at the intersection of Austrian economics and marketing, the relevance of Menger and Mises’ insights is undeniable. Austrian principles provide us with a practical framework for understanding consumer behavior – especially in markets driven by subjective value, such as luxury goods. The success of brands like Hermès is a testament to the power of subjective value and purposeful action, concepts that should be at the core of any marketing strategy.

By embracing the complexity of human behavior and rejecting one-size-fits-all models, we can create campaigns that resonate deeply with consumers. The Austrian School teaches us that value is fluid, personal and often intangible. And it is this nuanced understanding that allows us to develop strategies that go beyond selling products: we create experiences that tap into the desires that drive human action.

By Sheisoe

Related Post